A service of the

Download article as PDF

There is a commonly held notion that higher fixed investment allows one to have it all – a higher labour productivity, a higher wage growth and higher or at least sustained returns on capital. However, experience shows that capital accumulation has led to a decline in total capital productivity with resulting pressures on capital returns – which have been largely offset by keeping wage growth subdued. This suggests that more policy focus should instead be placed on investment aimed at boosting total factor productivity through innovation and diffusion of technological progress so that gains in productivity and remuneration may be felt by both labour and capital.

In contrast to the ongoing debates on labour productivity, capital productivity has generally not received a lot of attention. Although the two concepts are highly interrelated, they are also quite different. Labour productivity, which measures output per working hour and is an important determinant of standards of living, typically rises alongside fixed investment. Capital productivity, which measures output per capital services,1 or simply output per quality-adjusted capital stock, is in turn a key driving force for savings, investment and economic development. Given that the scarcest input is by its very nature most productive, there is some trade-off between the two productivity measures. That said, capital and labour productivity can rise in tandem if there is an improvement in total factor productivity (TFP). Higher TFP implies a higher efficiency of the overall production process, allowing a higher level of output for given levels of labour and capital.

Ignoring prices, overall real capital productivity2 in G7 economies has declined markedly over the past three decades, with only a brief period of improvement during the economic boom of 2003-07 and more recently in the aftermath of the global financial crisis (Figure 1).

Figure 1
Real capital productivity, total economy
Index, 2009=100; G7: non-weighted average
Real capital productivity, total economy

Source: OECD.

In 2017, capital productivity was down on average by 10% since 2007 and by 20% since mid-1990s.

This secular decline in capital productivity is also apparent across major non-financial market industries, especially in construction and non-financial business services, but also in manufacturing (Figure 2).3 It is only the information and communication (IC) sector that showed a long-run uptrend. The worst performing sub-industries have been retail within trade and nondurable goods within manufacturing. In contrast, capital productivity in durable goods manufacturing has turned around in the 2000s showing an uptrend thereafter, while the intermediate goods sector has shown relative stability.

Figure 2
Real capital productivity by sector, G7 excluding Japan and Canada
Index, 2009=100; non-weighted average
Real capital productivity by sector, G7 excluding Japan and Canada

Note: After 1998 information and communication (IC) consists of (i) publishing, audiovisual and broadcasting activities; (ii) telecommunications; (iii) IT and other information services. Before 1998, as the dashed line indicates, IC composition varied across countries, but predominantly consisted of post and telecommunications, e.g. IC included postal services in the US until 1998 and in Germany until 1991, which afterwards has been included in the transportation sector.

Source: EU KLEMS, World KLEMS, author’s calculations.

Decline in capital productivity: Underlying forces

Why does capital productivity fall as investment picks up? First, investment booms often result in some capacity underutilisation. This may reflect temporary factors such as the need for additional investment during a gradual buildup of large projects or the need for resource reorganisation and training. But some effects, such as inelastic total demand, are more lasting. For example, building more supermarkets or hotels in a neighbourhood may not lead to a proportionate increase in the overall demand. Also, the rise in new technology-led businesses has reduced the appeal for goods and services produced by old industries, e.g. while digitisation has brought about capital-efficient e-commerce, it has left spare capacity in high street retailers. External forces, such as increased foreign competition, have also negatively affected demand, both domestic and external, in some sectors.

But even if new fixed investment is utilised to full capacity, the law of diminishing marginal returns implies that, at industry level, raising capital per workforce eventually leads to a lower marginal and average capital productivity, all else equal. This is directly linked to the decreasing marginal product of capital in many industries, i.e. each extra unit of capital tends to generate less output, all else equal. Providing an employee with a second laptop does not necessarily increase his output, for example. Moreover, this extra output per extra capital is highest when capital stock is relatively low. In other words, the scarcer the capital, the higher the capital productivity. That is why some of the most attractive investment opportunities are often found in less developed countries. Similarly, according to the famous Solow model, accumulation of capital alone cannot yield lasting economic progress. TFP growth is the ultimate driver of economic growth and productivity of both labour and capital.

Growth accounting, based on EU KLEMS data, allows for the measurement of the contribution to economic growth from quality-adjusted capital, skill-adjusted labour and technological change. By extension, a change in capital productivity can be illustrated as the sum of a positive contribution from TFP growth and a negative contribution from the rise in the capital to labour ratio, called capital deepening (Figure 3).4

Figure 3
Contributions to capital productivity growth, G7 excluding Japan and Canada
Percentage points; non-weighted averages across countries and time
Contributions to capital productivity growth, G7 excluding Japan and Canada

Source: EU KLEMS, author’s calculations.

In the long-run, capital productivity in G7 countries has declined as the pace of capital deepening has by and large outpaced TFP growth. The only instances when TFP growth was sufficiently strong enough that investment and capital productivity (and labour productivity) performed well were the boom years (2003-07) for manufacturing, or the information and communication sector more broadly.5 In recent years, capital productivity has stabilised and even edged up in some countries, reflecting stalling capital deepening. The latter offset anemic or even negative TFP growth.

Capital deepening

Over the past decades, capital in G7 economies has become increasingly more abundant relative to labour,6 reflecting a more rapid accumulation of capital relative to growth in employment, and, in some cases, even a decline in employment. In some sectors, employment, measured as hours worked, fell alongside diminishing output, but the widespread decline in manufacturing employment (since the 1970s in European countries and since the early 2000s in the US) contrasted the continued increase in gross value added, suggesting that labour automation has played a role. This has changed post-crisis, as capital deepening in G7 economies stalled.

Figure 4
Change in capital and labour inputs, G7 excluding Japan and Canada
Percentage change in capital services and total hours worked
Change in capital and labour inputs, G7 excluding Japan and Canada

Source: EU KLEMS, author’s calculations.

While employment recovery was particularly weak in manufacturing, construction and trade in the five G7 countries under consideration (in 2015 it was still below 2007 level), the recovery was even shallower in investment, with quality-adjusted capital stock barely rising in the eight years until 2015 across all six sectors (see Figure 4).

Despite the recent pause, there are reasons to expect that capital deepening will likely resume in the years ahead:

  • Temporary cyclical forces appear to have played a role in the recent slowdown, such as high levels of uncertainty and capacity underutilisation holding investment. Investment growth picked up in 2017-18 in several countries, and the European Commission projects an increase in the ratio of net stock of capital to employed persons in all G7 countries in 2020-21.7
  • In the longer run, worsening demographics (the labour force is already declining in Japan, Germany and Italy and slowing elsewhere) will further intensify pressure for labour automation, reinforced by recent technological advances in computer power, artificial intelligence and robotics.

But there are also reasons to believe that capital deepening will not resume the pace of the 1980s or 1990s:

  • The growth in capital intensity, i.e. the capital to labour ratio, has been decelerating in Japan and European countries already for several decades.
  • When capital stock relative to labour and incomes is high, a large proportion of investment goes just to replenish capital that becomes outdated, broken and obsolete.
  • Moreover, the rise of the ‘sharing economy’, from cloud computing to coworking spaces, suggests that capital may be more efficiently used and thus less abundant.
  • Meanwhile, the shift of labour to (so far) more labour-intensive service sectors, if continued, points to an overall economy that is shallower in capital.

While a return in capital deepening will be a welcome development for labour productivity, pressures on capital productivity will resurface, especially if TFP growth remains subdued.

Higher investment: A cause or a symptom of TFP growth?

Contrary to some beliefs, higher fixed investment is generally not a solution to weak TFP growth,8 and in fact, may act as a drag on TFP in the short run due to negative effects of the (temporary) underutilisation of newly invested capital. But then, why do investment growth and TFP growth show a high correlation over the longer run? In the G7 countries, for example, the correlation between TFP growth and investment growth was 0.8 over the 1980-2017 period. An explanation is that investment and TFP are both pro-cyclical: they tend to rise in economic upswings and decrease in economic downturns. In expansionary periods, such as in the years 2003-07, booming demand conditions encourage investment and boost TFP via improved aggregate capacity utilisation of labour and capital. Likewise, the sharp ensuing recession after the global financial crisis left sizeable spare capacity and little business’ appetite for new capital outlays. The role of demand can be illustrated by the US example: the correlation between fixed investment growth and non-adjusted TFP growth in the US over the period 1985-2017 was 0.6, but only 0.2 when using a capacity-adjusted TFP series (Figure 5).

Figure 5
Fixed investment and TFP in the US
Percentage change, q/q, annualised, 5-year moving average
Fixed investment and TFP in the US

Source: FRBSF, Haver Analytics.

Sometimes, economic and investment booms originate from positive shocks to (capacity-adjusted) TFP itself. In the past, such positive TFP shocks resulted from new business models and production processes (e.g. assembly lines, outsourcing), technological advancements (e.g. the Internet, personal computer), regulatory environment changes (e.g. reforms increasing efficiency and competition in product and labour markets), among other factors. These forces have been observed to drive growth of output, incomes and investment. For example, economic acceleration in the new EU accession countries in the mid-2000s or East Germany in the 1990s after the fall of the Berlin Wall were in part driven by structural reforms that focused on market liberalisation and privatisation, and a reduction of supply side bottlenecks (Figure 6). In turn, the Internet and rapid advancements in computer technology served as an engine for growth in the US during the 1990s boom.

Figure 6
TFP growth, total economy
Percentage, average
TFP growth, total economy

Source: OECD.

Yet certain investment, such as that in research and development (R&D) and technology-embodying capital, is not only a symptom of but also a catalyst for TFP growth. R&D is critical for stimulating the learning and innovation process, while intellectual property products and ICT capital (information technology equipment, communications equipment and software) help promote knowledge transfer, technology diffusion and efficiency spillovers across industries, including trade, transportation and manufacturing. Information and communication technologies allow companies to streamline production, distribution and administrative processes and produce superior goods and services with less resources and in less time. There is significant empirical evidence, at both the macro and micro level, that confirms positive spillovers to TFP growth arising from investment in R&D, and notably (cumulative) investment in ICT capital.9 Figure 7 and Figure 8 show that countries and sectors with the highest average TPF growth during 2002-07, notably information and communication followed by manufacturing, also had the highest levels of ICT capital intensity.

Figure 7
Capital intensity in IC, manufacturing and services
Capital to hours worked ratio, average 2010-15, in USD 2010 prices
Capital intensity in IC, manufacturing and services

Note:Services include transportation, trade, food and accommodation.

Source: EU KLEMS, author’s calculations.

Figure 8
TFP growth in IC, manufacturing and services
Percentage change, average
TFP growth in IC, manufacturing and services

Note:Services include transportation, trade, food and accommodation.

Source: EU KLEMS.

That said, post-crisis slowdown in TFP growth is visible across the five G7 countries considered, especially in the US (TFP growth in the US in 2011-17 fell to one-fourth of the 1996-2005 pace even after adjusting for utilisation), irrespective of its much higher ICT capital intensity (Figure 8). Moreover, ICT investment slowed in tandem with TPF, notably in the US, which is considered to be at the technology frontier (ICT investment growth halved from the 1990s pace), sparking a debate about the fading dividends of the Internet revolution and earlier advancements in semiconductor and hardware industries.

There are reasons to believe that there remain untapped investment opportunities in technological capital. To begin with, European countries still lag behind the US in ICT capital, suggesting sizeable potential TFP gains from investment into existing technologies. But even in the US, the evidence suggests room for further technology diffusion. The OECD finds that TFP growth remains strong within the most productive firms but the gap between the others has widened.10 Finally, recent advances in computing power, artificial intelligence and other breakthrough technologies offer hope for a new wave of technology-led productivity renaissance, albeit with time lags.11

Capital productivity and capital returns

The implications of declining capital productivity are far-reaching, as capital productivity represents the key source of returns on productive business capital.12 Other elements include output prices, prices of inputs (raw materials, intermediate goods, cost of capital), wages and taxes. All else equal, lower levels of capital productivity imply lower capital returns. Following the methodology by the Federal Reserve System and Bureau of Economic Analysis, pre-tax capital returns on productive capital for the five G7 countries considered13 are calculated here as the ratio of the net operating surplus to the net stock of capital.14 Across industries, percentage point changes in aggregate capital returns show positive correlation with percentage changes in capital productivity (Figure 9).

Figure 9
Capital productivity and returns, G7 excluding Japan and Canada
Real capital productivity; pre-tax net returns on net fixed assets
Capital productivity and returns, G7 excluding Japan and Canada

Source: EU KLEMS, OECD, author’s calculations.

Figure 10
Shares of capital returns and income, G7 excluding Japan and Canada
Percentage; pre-tax net returns; share of value added at factor costs
Shares of capital returns and income, G7 excluding Japan and Canada

Source: EU KLEMS, OECD, author’s calculations.

Capital returns in 2011-15 were generally lower than in the pre-crisis 1998-2007 period across industries, but at the same time fared better than capital productivity (Figure 10). Returns declined in trade as well as food and accommodation, in parallel with lower productivity. More stable returns in manufacturing were in sync with more stable productivity. However, the rise in capital returns in construction and the decline in returns in the information and communication sector contrasted their respective developments in capital productivity.15

There are two possible explanations for these divergences:

  1. Changes in relative prices (of output, capital, other inputs) led to better or worse capital productivity metrics in nominal terms.16 The manufacturing sector benefitted from the decline in energy prices since 2014, while the construction sector profited from a sharp price appreciation of real estate fixed assets, notably post-crisis. In contrast, technology cost deflation has led to a decline in capital returns in the information and communication sector.

    Falling prices of capital embodying technology makes innovation more inclusive. The flip side of it is that declining ICT prices imply capital losses for the owners of the old equipment and pressures on output prices for ICT producers. A rapid technological change implies a much higher rate of depreciation and obsolescence for ICT capital than that of traditional assets.17 For example, buildings not only have lower depreciation rates but have seen significant price appreciation over time. For that reason, in order for ICT investment to boost capital productivity and returns, it needs to generate TFP spillovers to offset both pressures on real capital productivity from capital deepening and capital losses resulting from the technological change.

  2. The pressures from lower capital productivity were offset by subdued wage growth, at below the pace of labour productivity growth, allowing for an increase in capital income shares. Looking at the country group averages across industries, the changes in average pre-tax nominal capital returns in 2011-15 versus 1998-2007 at least partly reflected capital income shares. It is interesting to note that variation in capital income shares is at least partially explained by capital intensity (explanatory power is 85% in manufacturing in the US). In individual countries, increases in capital shares have contributed to better returns in manufacturing as well as information and communication sectors in the US, Germany and the UK, and in construction in Germany. A rise in income shares supporting capital returns also holds for the non-financial corporate sector that does not have mixed income bias.18

This analysis answers or reformulates some of the prevailing questions in academia and media:

  • Why do non-financial corporates not invest despite high returns?19 It is because the key factors behind strong returns are likely non-sustainable, notably post-crisis appreciation of real estate prices, suppressed wages and rising income shares.
  • Why do income shares not rise despite slow growth in investment? Capital income shares at least partly reflect the rise in capital intensity, and the fact that compensation is demanded not by newly invested capital but also by the old (costly) capital.

Focus on innovation and technological progress

While it is often argued that investment is a recipe for both higher wages and higher corporate profits, such discussions miss an important element of capital productivity. All else equal, investment does boost labour productivity, whereas rising capital intensity weighs on capital productivity and capital returns. In fact, companies managed to sustain capital returns in the past by subduing real wage growth with rising capital income shares. It is only TFP growth that allows for the increases in returns and productivity of both labour and capital. What is also missing from these discussions is the focus on investment that has the potential to boost TFP. Unlike traditional physical capital, investment in ICT capital, R&D and intellectual property products allow companies to shift to new technologies, more advanced capital and higher TFP levels.

In this context, governments should focus on policies that promote creation and diffusion of innovation and technological progress. Potential gains from investment in technology-embodying capital are particularly high in European countries, as they still lag significantly behind the US in both ICT investment flows and ICT capital stock relative to their economies. Europe should aim at creating favourable conditions for private ICT investment through tax incentives and trade policies, pro-competition reforms to product markets (notably services) and public spending on basic research and education.

  • 1 Capital services is the capital input into a production process and is estimated by weighing different types of productive capital stock corrected for efficiency loss and retirement with user costs, i.e. imputed rental prices.
  • 2 To measure capital productivity in real terms, this article uses the ratio of gross value added (GVA) volume to capital services volume, a measure generally preferred in academic literature. An alternative measure of real capital productivity – the ratio of GVA to real capital stock – suggests a similar long-run broad-based decline.
  • 3 The sectoral analysis focuses on five G7 countries (the US, Germany, France, Italy, the UK) and excludes Japan and Canada due to data limitations.
  • 4 Capital to labour ratio, the rise of which is called capital deepening, is calculated here as the ratio of capital services to labour services, i.e. quality-adjusted capital to skill-adjusted hours worked.
  • 5 At least from the late 1990s after the data adjustment.
  • 6 The long-run uptrend is apparent using different measures, including the ratio of capital services to total hours worked, capital services to skill-adjusted labour input, capital stock to total hours worked and capital stock to persons employed.
  • 7 See AMECO database.
  • 8 A.S. Englander, A. Gurney: Medium-term determinants of OECD productivity, OECD Economic Studies No. 22, Spring 1994, pp. 52-56.
  • 9 See D.J. Wilson: IT and Beyond: The Contribution of Heterogeneous Capital to Productivity, FRBSF Working Paper No. 2004-13, 2007; OECD: The Economic Impact of ICT: Measurement, Evidence and Implications, Paris 2004, OECD Publishing, p. 96; G. Adler, M.R.A. Duval, D. Furceri, K. Sinem, K. Koloskova, M. Poplawski-Ribeiro: Gone with the Headwinds: Global Productivity, IMF Staff Discussion Note No. 17/04, 2017.
  • 10 OECD: The Future of Productivity, Paris 2015, OECD Publishing.
  • 11 S. Basu, J.G. Fernald: Information and Communications Technology as a General-Purpose Technology: Evidence from U.S. Industry Data, FRBSF Economic Review, 2008, pp. 1-15; E. Brynjolfsson, D. Rock, C. Syverson: Artificial Intelligence and the Modern Productivity Paradox: A Clash of Expectations and Statistics, NBER Working Paper No. 24001, November 2017.
  • 12 Return on productive capital differs from financial returns, as the latter also includes prices of financial capital, i.e. stocks and bonds. See K.A. Petrick: Comparing NIPA Profits with S&P 500 Profits, in: Survey of Current Business, Vol. 81, No. 4, 2001, pp. 16-20.
  • 13 Sectoral analysis focuses on five G7 countries excluding Japan and Canada due to data limitations.
  • 14 Net operating surplus is a broad measure of corporate profits and is calculated as revenues minus costs of intermediate inputs, compensation of employees, taxes on production and imports less subsidies, and consumption of fixed capital from, but before subtracting financing costs and business transfer payments. Net capital stock measured as net fixed assets valued at current replacement cost, and thus, unlike in other studies, excludes inventories due to data limitations. See R.J. Corea, B.A. Retus: Returns for Domestic Nonfinancial Business, BEA Survey of Current Business, June 2015; P. Gomme, B. Ravicumar, P. Ruper: Secular Stagnation and Returns to Capital, Economic Synopses, Economic Synopses No. 19, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, 2015.
  • 15 The analysis focuses on changes in returns rather than on the comparison of return levels across sectors. For example, the rate of return in the construction sector may be inflated due to a sizable share of leased assets.
  • 16 Nominal or expenditure-oriented capital productivity is measured as the ratio of market value of output to cost of capital services; see McKinsey Global Institute: Capital Productivity, June 1996. Alternatively, nominal capital productivity can be measured as nominal GDP to depreciation / consumption of capital; see T. Weiß: Has the Decline in Productivity of Capital been Halted, in: Intereconomics, Vol. 33, No. 2, 1998, pp. 86-92, available at https://archive.intereconomics.eu/downloads/getfile.php?id=14.
  • 17 See D. Koszerek, K. Havik, K. Mc Morrow, W. Röger, F. Schönborn: An overview of the EU KLEMS Growth and Productivity Accounts, European Economy, Economic Papers No. 290, European Commission, 2007.
  • 18 In industrial accounts, proprietor’s income is being attributed to capital income.
  • 19 P. Gomme, B. Ravicumar, P. Ruper, op. cit.


DOI: 10.1007/s10272-019-0857-5